About F&D Subscribe Back Issues Write Us Copyright Information Free Email Notification Receive emails when we post new
items of interest to you. |
Letters to the editor
The controversy over oil funds I read with interest "Oil Funds: Problems Posing as Solutions?" by Jeffrey Davis, Rolando Ossowski, James Daniel, and Steven Barnett (December 2001). However, despite the substantial empirical and country research that went into the article, I believe that, with the right framework—for example, a cap on all borrowings, prudent liquidity management, and appropriate medium-term expenditure planning—oil funds would serve many public policy objectives. True, an oil fund cannot replace fiscal policy decisions (expenditure smoothing), but the long-term benefits of creating such a fund cannot be ignored. A well-managed oil fund (or any fund that sets aside a portion of surplus government revenues) can only be beneficial, especially in a developing country. Although I am not trying to simplify fiscal problems, the old adage of putting money away for a rainy day holds true even for countries! Any measure that discourages fiscal profligacy and encourages increased government saving can only benefit the country's population. The reason energy funds did not take off or were closed down, as stated in the article, is because of poor governance, corruption, or other such problems. If the choice were between not encouraging the creation of such funds (because of past experience) versus encouraging them, but with a sound framework, I would vote for the latter. The article also states that stabilization funds may face either continuous accumulation or rapid exhaustion of resources. True, but there is also the possibility that the fund might not even take off if the oil price outturn is much lower than the rules governing the transfer to such a fund. In that case, the government itself may have to borrow to get the fund going from the start!
P. Sudhakar
Adliya, Manama Bahrain Jeffrey Davis and Rolando Ossowski reply
Mauritius: A Case Study Arvind Subramanian's interesting article (December 2001), if anything, understates the uniqueness of Mauritius's achievements: a functioning pluralist democracy, consensual coalition politics, sustainable development, and a model welfare state. It also leaves unanswered the central question: who designed the viable economic strategy and how was the consensus between technocrats, bureaucrats, and politicians achieved in a multiethnic society? Nor does the article identify the key role played by a positive income and prices policy based on large and active trade unions with centralized wage bargaining coupled with price controls on socially sensitive wage-goods, which has helped maintain industrial peace, so vital for successful export performance. While the article rightly points to the role of the Chinese community in attracting investment by Hong Kong entrepreneurs, it overlooks the equally important role of the majority Indian diaspora in developing the offshore financial sector and attracting Indian investment and substantial technical assistance. The article correctly stresses the role of "strong domestic institutions"—a portmanteau concept covering all non-economic variables—as a major factor in Mauritius's enduring economic miracle, which recalls the memorable observation of the Nobel Laureate Robert Solow. How often all discussions of the sources of growth and development seem to end in a blaze of sociology, which also explains the stubbornly large residuals in all growth-accounting models.
Anand Chandavarkar
Formerly, IMF advisor Arvind Subramanian replies
|